ALL Metrics
-
Views
-
Downloads
Get PDF
Get XML
Cite
Export
Track
Research Article
Revised

Fertility transition in selected sub-Saharan African countries: the role of family planning programs

[version 2; peer review: 2 approved]
PUBLISHED 29 May 2020
Author details Author details
OPEN PEER REVIEW
REVIEWER STATUS

Abstract

Background: Change in fertility rate across societies is a complex process that involves changes in the demand for children, the diffusion of new attitudes about family planning and greater accessibility to contraception. Scholars have concentrated on a range of factors associated with fertility majorly at the national scale. However, considerably less attention has been paid to fertility preference - a pathway through which various variables act on fertility. It is understood that women have inherent fertility preferences which each they seek to achieve over her reproductive cycle. However, the service delivery enhancement levels and capacity across countries as integral pathways to this goal accomplishment stand on their way towards eventual outcomes. Precisely, the Sub-Saharan African countries’ disparities amid similarities in their population policies is a cause of concern.
Methods: Using Bongaarts reformulation of Easterlin conceptual scheme of 1985 on DHS data, the understanding of the current fertility transition in general would provide explanations to the observed fertility dynamics. This study therefore is an attempt to explain the current fertility transition through women’s fertility preference.
Results: Results reveal that fertility transition is diverse across sub-Saharan Africa; generally, on a decline course in most of the countries. The huge disparities in fertility preferences among women of reproductive age and its non-significant change in the implementation indices points at the service delivery performance underneath regarding the proportion of demand to family planning commodities satisfied. Service delivery indicators are integral to fertility preference achievement within households as well as a country’s overall positioning regarding fertility transition at the macroscale.
Conclusions: It is therefore plausible to conclude that the improvement of service delivery in general; precisely touching on the availability and the uptake of quality birth control technologies is one of the most feasible means through which countries can fast track their fertility transitions.

Keywords

Fertility, Preference Implementation index, family planning, Transition, Sub-Saharan Africa

Revised Amendments from Version 1

I have reworked the abstract section as per reviewers comments
I have beefed up literature and edited my citations to conform to the reviewers comments
I have also revised the discussions section to include FP/RH policy implications
I have also allowed for an objective review of the statistical analysis from one of the authors - Prof Alfred Agwanda

See the authors' detailed response to the review by Julianne Weis

Introduction

Change in fertility rate across societies is a complex process that involves changes in the demand for children, the diffusion of new attitudes about family planning and greater accessibility to contraception provided by family planning programs1,2. Debates about this transition in Sub-Saharan Africa have almost reached a consensus about its uniqueness since they began in the mid-1990s. The trajectory of African fertility transitions occurred earlier than anticipated if Africa had followed the non-African relationship between fertility and development3. However, the pace of decline in fertility rate at the time of onset of the transition in this rate was slower than the comparable pace at the onsets of non-African transitions. The key features of African fertility regimes indicate that at a given level of development, Africa’s fertility is higher, contraceptive use is lower, and desired family size is higher than in non-African less-developed countries1,2.

Fertility preference is anchored by service delivery advancement; precisely contraceptive uptake among modern societies. It is evident that contraceptive prevalence is rising with fertility subsequently falling across countries at varied intensities4. The speed within which these changes are occurring in countries points at the diverse entry periods of countries into transition1; which also is dependent on the levels of endowment within service delivery points. Underlying the changed contraceptive fertility behavior, there appears to have been a major shift in attitudes regarding desired family size overtime5. With the intention to lower births, the availability and advancement in contraceptive technology overtime as well as the improvement in the dispensation mechanisms of these vital birth regulation commodities through extensively devolved service delivery points is key1,6,7. It is clear that a direct correlation exists between contraceptive uptake and service delivery points including the continuum of care. In her studies of the Standard Days Method (SDM) as a component within the contraceptive method mix, Weis (2020) noted evidence of demonstrated high level acceptability of the method just as the others across diversity in demographic characteristics of users.

This raises two fundamentally interrelated concepts observed in a number of developing countries, namely: the extent to which changes in fertility levels are due to changes in fertility preference and the extent to which the observed fertility changes result from the ability of women to implement these fertility desires2. In this study we seek to add to our understanding of the fertility transition by examining how countries differ in their patterns of reproductive behavior. We specifically examine trends in the fertility desires and the extent at which the ability to implement fertility desires contributes to the prevailing fertility change.

Methods

Analytical model

Using all the trend data from Measure DHS gathered between 1986 and 2016 across sub-Saharan African countries (listed in Table 1), we apply2 a reformulation of810 a conceptual scheme in which the variable ‘fertility’ is measured by the total fertility rate (F0), a function of the supply of births (natural fertility), the demand for births (wanted fertility) and the degree of preference implementation index9. The latter in turn is dependent on cost of fertility regulation and cost of unwanted childbearing. The degree of preference implementation is the net result of a decision-making process in which couples weigh the cost of fertility regulation and the cost of unwanted pregnancy. Figure 1 shows the diagrammatic presentation.

Table 1. Trends in fertility preference estimates of selected Sub-Saharan African countries.

CountryDHS Survey
year
Total
fertility rate
Total wanted
fertility rate
Natural fertility (fertility rate in
absence of any contraception)
Index of preference
implementation
Angola2015–16 DHS6.24.997.210.45
Benin2011–12 DHS4.94.45.640.6
Benin2006 DHS5.74.896.890.59
Benin2001 DHS5.64.896.910.65
Benin1996 DHS65.287.210.63
Burkina Faso2010 DHS65.247.190.61
Burkina Faso2003 DHS5.95.216.870.58
Burkina Faso1998–99 DHS6.45.717.280.56
Burkina Faso1993 DHS6.55.88.710.76
Burundi2010 DHS6.45.038.240.57
Burundi1987 DHS6.95.77.570.36
Cameroon2011 DHS5.14.556.70.75
Cameroon2004 DHS54.726.80.86
Cameroon1998 DHS4.84.655.980.89
Cameroon1991 DHS5.85.66.940.85
Chad2014–15 DHS6.46.096.80.56
Chad2004 DHS6.36.227.10.91
Chad1996–97 DHS6.46.216.680.6
Congo2011–12 DHS5.14.939.370.96
Congo2005 DHS4.84.678.760.97
Congo Democratic Republic2013–14 DHS6.65.638.330.64
Congo Democratic Republic2007 DHS6.35.647.980.72
Cote d'Ivoire2011–12 DHS54.756.140.82
Cote d'Ivoire1998–99 DHS5.24.876.140.74
Cote d'Ivoire1994 DHS5.34.960.63
Ethiopia2016 DHS4.63.887.260.79
Ethiopia2011 DHS4.83.976.780.7
Ethiopia2005 DHS5.44.056.350.41
Ethiopia2000 DHS5.54.5660.34
Ghana2014 DHS4.23.655.770.74
Ghana2008 DHS43.575.260.75
Ghana2003 DHS4.43.85.920.72
Ghana1998 DHS4.43.835.670.69
Ghana1993 DHS5.24.36.560.6
Ghana1988 DHS6.45.367.370.48
Guinea2012 DHS5.14.845.410.55
Guinea2005 DHS5.75.146.280.51
Guinea1999 DHS5.55.065.870.46
Kenya2014 DHS3.93.089.550.87
Kenya2008–09 DHS4.63.248.580.75
Kenya2003 DHS4.93.558.180.71
Kenya1998 DHS4.73.297.80.69
Kenya1993 DHS5.43.628.10.6
Kenya1989 DHS6.74.139.230.5
Lesotho2014 DHS3.32.638.550.89
Lesotho2009 DHS3.32.616.340.81
Lesotho2004 DHS3.52.815.650.76
Liberia2013 DHS4.74.195.920.71
Liberia2007 DHS5.24.445.880.47
Liberia1986 DHS6.76.047.170.42
Madagascar2008–09 DHS4.83.758.090.76
Madagascar2003–04 DHS5.247.190.62
Madagascar1997 DHS64.537.480.5
Madagascar1992 DHS6.14.467.350.43
Malawi2015–16 DHS4.43.3211.110.86
Malawi2010 DHS5.73.9710.760.75
Malawi2004 DHS64.48.980.65
Malawi2000 DHS6.34.479.160.61
Malawi1992 DHS6.75.617.720.48
Mali2012–13 DHS6.15.426.820.51
Mali2006 DHS6.65.857.20.44
Mali2001 DHS6.85.877.410.4
Mali1995–96 DHS6.75.967.190.4
Mali1987 DHS7.16.357.460.32
Mozambique2011 DHS5.94.956.690.46
Mozambique2003 DHS5.54.917.430.77
Mozambique1997 DHS5.25.035.520.65
Namibia2013 DHS3.62.918.420.87
Namibia2006–07 DHS3.62.688.220.83
Namibia2000 DHS4.22.937.580.73
Namibia1992 DHS5.44.437.660.7
Niger2012 DHS7.67.198.860.75
Niger2006 DHS76.727.90.76
Niger1998 DHS7.26.837.860.64
Niger1992 DHS76.717.330.53
Nigeria2013 DHS5.55.166.50.75
Nigeria2008 DHS5.75.246.70.69
Nigeria2003 DHS5.75.316.540.68
Nigeria1990 DHS65.656.390.53
Rwanda2014–15 DHS4.23.269.180.84
Rwanda2010 DHS4.63.269.710.79
Rwanda2007–08 DHS5.53.788.750.65
Rwanda2005 DHS6.14.357.420.43
Rwanda2000 DHS5.84.646.70.44
Rwanda1992 DHS6.24.717.910.53
Senegal2016 DHS4.74.596.320.93
Senegal2015 DHS4.94.766.430.91
Senegal2014 DHS54.776.460.87
Senegal2012–13 DHS5.34.926.480.76
Senegal2010–11 DHS54.75.770.72
Senegal2005 DHS5.34.926.030.66
Senegal1997 DHS5.75.096.560.59
Senegal1992–93 DHS65.46.50.46
Senegal1986 DHS6.45.747.230.56
Sierra Leone2013 DHS4.94.455.90.69
Sierra Leone2008 DHS5.14.45.570.4
Tanzania2015–16 DHS5.24.518.550.83
Tanzania2010 DHS5.44.598.320.78
Tanzania2004–05 DHS5.74.787.80.7
Tanzania1999 DHS5.64.767.560.7
Tanzania1996 DHS5.84.827.140.58
Tanzania1991–92 DHS6.25.46.940.48
Togo2013–14 DHS4.84.156.020.65
Togo1998 DHS5.24.536.840.71
Togo1988 DHS6.45.449.780.78
Uganda2011 DHS6.24.418.930.6
Uganda2006 DHS6.74.728.840.52
Uganda2000–01 DHS6.94.978.990.52
Uganda1995 DHS6.95.328.130.44
Uganda1988–89 DHS7.46.177.790.24
Zambia2013–14 DHS5.34.2310.60.83
Zambia2007 DHS6.24.7510.620.75
Zambia2001–02 DHS5.94.619.060.71
Zambia1996 DHS6.15.068.290.68
Zambia1992 DHS6.55.537.690.55
Zimbabwe2015 DHS43.4312.550.94
Zimbabwe2010–11 DHS4.13.4910.170.91
Zimbabwe2005–06 DHS3.83.229.850.91
Zimbabwe1999 DHS43.438.80.89
Zimbabwe1994 DHS4.33.678.440.87
Zimbabwe1988 DHS5.44.389.640.81
11ab439f-17f8-4d77-915e-ed462eb73d7e_figure1.gif

Figure 1. Variants in the supply-demand model.

Relationship between variables

According to Bongaarts (1993):

Fn=F0/C(1)

C is an index ranging from 0 to 1 measuring the proportional reduction in Fn attributed to deliberate birth control mechanisms. Birth control not only confined to contraception also encompass induced abortion practices though always ignored in studies. F0 data is always available and hence the only additional task required is to compute Fn in (i) with an estimate of C. Bongaarts further provided a procedure for deducing C, with an approach though the limitation was the unavailability of data. Hence:

C=11.02×U(2)

Where U is the fraction of women in marriage practicing all forms of birth regulation except during the post-partum in-fecundity period. The error associated with this is negligible hence ignored sometimes. By substituting C in Equation 1 above yields the anticipated approximation of natural total fertility.

Fw computation: According to Bongaarts, the favoured approach is dependent on the equation below:

FW=FW+1.09Wm(4049)(3)

Where Fw is the proportion of women who want more children, equaling the resulting total fertility after deleting all births to women who want no more children at the time of the survey and Wm (40–49) is the proportion of women in union aged from 40 to 49 who want no more births.

These two equations helped normalize the biases in order to compute the respective Fn and Fw trends across the regions. With most of the erratic curves expected, a normalization process using the natural logarithms of the equation was applied to give meaning to the various trend curves.

Ip is derived from a synthesis of past studies. It begins from the fact that all social and economic factors of fertility operate through a unified pack of proximate factors to exert an impact on fertility8. Easterlin’s economic approach is a model of behavioural and biological factors affecting fertility in developing countries. The model consists of three central concepts: demand for children; the potential supply of children, and the momentary and psychic costs of contraception. According to the model, women whose potential supply of births exceeds demand would consider contraception, taking into consideration the costs involved while choosing suitable family planning methods8,9.

The model is simple and attractive; however, it cannot address dynamic issues and has not succeeded in quantifying these factors in acceptable manner2. Emerging from the model is the fact that fertility (measured using F0) is a function of three determinants namely: supply of births (Fn), demand for births (Fw) and the degree of Ip (Figure 1).

Supply of births (Fn) is measured as natural total fertility. Fn infers the rate of birthing likely to prevail minus the premeditated attempts by spouses to limit their number of children. Demand for births (Fw) is the wanted total fertility defined as the rate of prevailing childbearing after eliminating all unwanted births. Under normal circumstances, it is simply calculated as F0 while eliminating the unwanted births from the numerator. Unwanted births are births occurring after an achievement of the ideal family size. Any births that are mistimed though occurring before the achievement of the desired family size are considered wanted births as well.

The degree of Ip is an index from zero value to unity. Its level of implementation implies the net result of decision-making process. This is the state in which a spouse ponders the cost of fertility regulation as they consider costs of bearing an unwanted child to its end. In general, the index has an inverse variation to the cost of fertility regulation as well as a reverse correlation to the unwanted births. If couples fully implement their fertility preference, the index is equal to unity. This signifies that no unwanted births occur as actual fertility corresponds to Fw. Conversely, if the index is equal to zero, the observed fertility equals Fn, that is, fertility in the absence of any deliberate fertility control assuming women remain sexually active over their reproductive cycles. The value of the index at play stipulates the position where actual fertility falls as dictated by the range set between wanted and Fn parameter levels.

F0 gives the estimate of the number of children a woman would have by the end of childbearing if she were to pass through her reproductive cycle at the customary age specific birth rates. The model shows that the operation of these variables determines the level of fertility in a community or households. In this variant of the original Easterlin and Crimmins (1985) model, infant and child mortality dynamics affects the desired fertility rather than Fn. Women are deemed to possess precise desired fertility size translated and actualized into numbers through subsequent births after considering past child losses and risks related to future child deaths as well.

According to this variant, as development occurs, the trend in prevailing fertility transforms to become a function of the equilibrium between the Fw, Fn and the degree of fertility Ip. Fw is expected to decline over time, as a result of the changes associated with the costs and benefits of child bearing9, as well as reductions in the infant-child mortality. Ip rises as fertility regulation costs decline; with the benefit of fertility regulation focusing on the elimination of any unwanted births8. According to 8, the relationship between these variables under discussions and fertility can be expressed in statistical form as follows:

F0=Fw+Fu(4)

Where Fu is the unwanted fertility (which can simply be expressed as F0 – Fw).

Fu=(FnFw)×(1Ip)(5)

Where Ip has a range of 0 to 1. With full Ip, Ip = 1 (which implies that Fu = 0 and F0 = Fw) and Ip = 0 with no prefer Ip (This implies a substantial level of unwanted childbearing and F0 = Fn). Noted here is that as defined by Bongaarts, Fn here is not the same as in total fecundity as in the Bongaarts proximate determinants but taken to mean fertility level achieved in absence of contraception8.

Fu is a function of the difference between supply and demand, and the degree of Ip.

Substitution of Equation 5 in Equation 6 yields:

F=Fw×Ip+Fn×(1Ip)(6)

Noting that Fn is given by:

Fn=F0/C

Where C implies an index ranging from 0 to 1 measuring the reduction in proportional of Fn attributable to deliberate birth control is estimated as:

C=11.02×U

Where U represents the proportion of married women who were practicing contraception at the time of survey. It is measured as the number of married women using contraceptive method to the total number of married women. The values for U and C can be used to estimate Fn

Rearranging Equation 6 gives:

Ip=(FnFo)/(FnFw)(7)

Equation 7 can now be used to estimate the degree of Ip once Fn (fertility in absence of contraception), actual fertility and Fw are known. One thing to note is that the estimation of Fw, as previously done overtime contain traits of upward bias as per the recent observation. An alternative estimation of Fw from Bongaarts model detail that the average Fw derived from the wanted status of births as reported by women was 2.8, indicating that this measure of wanted fertility contains an average upward bias of 0.4 birth.

The analysis consists of two stages. First, we computed the degree of Ip within the variable categories overtime from Fn, Fw and F0. F0 and Fw as a series of indicators are provided by the various country specific DHS reports. This involves compiling all the components of the index within the equation so as to come with the actual figures per the subsequent time intervals. The component variables are Fn, Fw computed to form the degree of Ip. Further correlation analysis between the degree of Ip and the unmet need to contraception, conducted using SPSS v18, was run.

Decomposition of fertility trends

According to Bongaarts (1993), the core objective of the demand framework lies in the identification of the causes of fertility decline in a population, with proceeding comparative analysis providing worthwhile insights yet not achieving its sole objective. Turning to the issue at hand, the decomposition of the variations in fertility and to abridge the methodological exposition, trends therefore should inform the basis of focus between two points in time, i.e. T1 and T2 running up to the determinants. The derivation of the decomposition equation also warrants the introduction of the variables listed in Table 2.

Table 2. Fertility decomposition.

VariableObservation point
Time PeriodsT1 T2
Total FertilityF1 F2
Natural FertilityFn1 Fn2
Wanted FertilityFw1 Fw2
Index of ImplementationIp1 Ip2

Source: Bongaarts (1993)

The decline in fertility between the two periods is F1-F2, conveyed by substitution as

F1F2=[Fw1Ip1+Fn1(1-Ip1)][Fw2IP2+Fn2(1-Ip2)](8)

The above equation therefore can be written as below

ΔF=ΔFwĪp+ΔIp(Ѓwn)+ΔFn(1-ĪP)(9)

In Equation 8: ∆F, ∆Fw, ∆Fn and ∆Ip are the change within F, Fw, Fn and Ip respectively.

In Equation 9: Ѓw, Ѓn and Īp are the mean values of correspondingly, Fw, Fn and Ip. For example, the mean of the degree of implementation index (Īp) is: - [0.5(Ip1 + Ip2)]

Īp implies the average of the Degree of Fertility Implementation Index (Ip). The influence of change in wanted (∆Fw ) as well as the natural (∆Fn) fertility to prevailing fertility change hinge on the average extent or degree of implementation. Consequently, the outcome of fertility from every shift registered on the degree of fertility implementation index is determined by the corresponding mean change between Fn and Fwwn). This function requires two successive points in the estimates of the parameter measurers i.e. F0, natural and Fw including the implementation index as well within the population under consideration. It is this function that is used to determine the extent to which implementation of fertility desires contributes to fertility transition (Table 4).

Results

Decomposition of fertility change and the contribution of Fw and Ip

As Table 1 shows the trend change in fertility parameters measurers, Table 3 further shows the decomposition of fertility changes among countries with two or more surveys. Results reveal there are indeed substantial variations between countries in terms of fertility preference parameter measurers as well as the implementation indices by countries. These results clearly indicate the important role played by the changes in Ip, Fw and Fn. Converse to the expected, eight countries actually increased their F0 over the period 1986–2016. In six out of the eight countries where fertility increased, there was a decline in degree of Ip. Subsequently, in five of the eight countries there was an increase in Fw. The largest decline in fertility rate occurred in Rwanda, Malawi, Kenya and Ethiopia. The four countries subsequently had the greatest contribution of the degree of Ip to fertility decline. On the same note the greatest contribution of Fw decline to fertility change occurred in Malawi, Rwanda and Kenya.

Table 3. Contribution of wanted fertility rate and preference implementation index to fertility change in selected Sub-Saharan African countries.

CountrySurveysChange in FoChange in FoAbsolute
Contribution to Fo
Change
Percent
Contribution to
Fo Change
BaselineLastGapFoTwFnIpTwFnIp
Rwanda2005201491.890.69-0.641.8437-3497
Malawi 20042015111.590.82-0.521.351-3382
Kenya20032014111.000.45-0.290.8445-2984
Ethiopia 20052016110.820.10-0.361.0845-2984
Benin 20012011100.700.310.48-0.084468-12
Uganda20002011110.680.310.030.3446450
Guinea2005201270.600.160.410.030.34464
Senegal20052016110.590.26-0.060.3845-1065
Zambia20012013120.590.29-0.350.6550-60111
Namibia20002013130.560.02-0.170.713-30127
Lesotho20042014100.510.15-0.020.3829-374
Liberia2007201360.510.15-0.020.3829-374
Mali2006201260.500.200.20.1414019
Tanzania20042015110.490.21-0.180.4642-3694
Madagascar2003200850.420.17-0.280.5341-66125
Nigeria20032013100.420.110.010.0937-3497
Cote d'Ivoire 19982011130.210.0900.1147053
Sierra Leone2008201350.20-0.03-0.150.38-14-74188
Ghana20032014110.200.110.040.04572122
Cameroon2004201170.190.14-0.02-0.23-17926305
Burkina Faso200320107-0.08-0.02-0.130.0519139-58
Chad2004201410-0.09-0.100.08-0.28-93-77270
Zimbabwe2005201510-0.10-0.19-0.020.24121126-147
Congo200520116-0.31-0.25-0.02-0.0480714
Congo DR200720136-0.31-0.01-0.11-0.2-23766
Mozambique200320118-0.40-0.03-0.29-0.666-71165
Niger200620126-0.60-0.36-0.24-0.0159392

F0, total fertility rate.

Table 4. Fertility change contribution.

Change (∆) in key measuresContribution to fertility
decline (∆F)
∆Fn ∆Fn(1- Īp)
∆Fw ∆F× Īp
Degree of ∆Ip ∆Ip(Average Fw - Average Fn)

Source: Bongaarts (1993). Fn, natural fertility; Fw, wanted fertility; Ip, fertility implementation index.

In absolute values, Rwanda, Malawi and Kenya experienced the highest fertility changes as well, while Niger, Mozambique and DRC experienced an increase in fertility rate within the periods 1986–2016. Looking at the contributions made by each of the fertility parameters, the fertility preference (Fw) and the degree of Ip are the reasons for the variations in the changes in fertility. Rwanda registered a 37% decrease in its average wanted fertility desires, with a corresponding degree of Ip of 97% (Table 2). Malawi and Kenya on the same note registered a reduction in Fw of 51% and 54% and corresponding implementation indices of 82% and 84%, respectively.

Figure 2 highlights the graphical correlation between Ip and unmet need for family planning. There is an inverse correlation between Ip and the unmet need for family planning. High unmet need for contraception leads to a low implementation index, since contraception is the sole contributing factor to fertility regulation (also referred to as the extent of Ip). This is because the extent of contraceptive availability and subsequent utilization of contraceptives is what defines Ip level. The absence of these essential birth control commodities leads to non-implementation of family planning, thereby failing to restrain Fn.

11ab439f-17f8-4d77-915e-ed462eb73d7e_figure2.gif

Figure 2. Correlation between implementation index and unmet need for family planning.

Figure 3 echoes the performance of Ip in facilitating the reduction of fertility by each of the countries within the periods under study. Ethiopia, Rwanda and Sierra Leone are the three countries where Ip has most contributed to the fertility decline. However, in some countries, the limited or non-implementation of fertility led to the index not facilitating any declines in F0, thereby allowing the natural increase to take its course. These countries were Mozambique, Chad, Cameroun, Democratic Republic of Congo, Togo, Benin, and Congo Brazzaville.

11ab439f-17f8-4d77-915e-ed462eb73d7e_figure3.gif

Figure 3. Percent change in preference implementation since 2000.

Discussion and conclusion

Based on the fertility preference and implementation indicators, fertility transition is indeed on course in a number of countries, going by the trend data for each country though at varied levels. The extent at which this occurs varies across countries, with each country exhibiting varied levels of implementation pointing at the service delivery state of advancement. The Fw and the degree of Ip are therefore key to the prevailing fertility in each country9. Countries where populations desired or Fw are in decline over time are believed to be high in their drive to lower their overall F0 supported by the state of the service providers.

The suppressed desired or wanted fertility rates correspond to high index of implementation subsequently exhibiting the highest transition changes. The prevailing F0 of a country therefore depends on the interplay between the fertility desires and the degree of fertility preference implementation index which is dependent on the availability of family planning commodities (proportion of demand satisfied). Reduction in fertility hence demands low desired fertility and high index of implementation simultaneously. This implies that those countries with only one high parameter performance (i.e. either suppressed wanted fertility or high implementation index) among the two exhibits only but between moderate to limited reduction in fertility change.

Further, the generally observed decline in the indices of fertility (i.e. F0, Fn, Fw and Ip) confirms the strength of the service delivery especially the family planning program efforts by the various stakeholders in making birth control technologies available (to curb the unmet need thereby satisfying demand), accessible and affordable to their populace as well as improved contraceptive technology. This is due to the fact that only birth control technologies are known to facilitate the implementation of couples’ fertility desires. Looking at the association between fertility preference implementation index and the unmet need for contraception (Figure 2), countries with high unmet need for contraception exhibit low values of fertility preference implementation index3 which in turn implies weak service delivery.

The converse is also true. The unmet need for contraception also reflects the proportion of demand satisfied. High unmet need for contraception is a function of lower total supply of family planning commodities required by all those women in need; implying low proportion of demand satisfied by the birth control commodities under the assumption that women of reproductive age are sexually active. This therefore leads to a surge in births as family planning is reduced owing to lower supplies of commodities than demanded. The unmet need has, however, progressively slowed over the years as births have reduced overtime in the majority of countries within the sub-Saharan Africa; reflected too by the surging implementation index overtime (Table 2).

This finding reflects the level of increase in sensitization, advocacy and public education by programs as well as the utilization of birth control technologies and improvements within the service delivery points. The wanted fertility, as a key parameter measure for the fertility change, relies heavily on the proportion of demand for contraception that is satisfied6. The wanted fertility rate is only achievable through the conscious attempt by spouses to deliberately control the number of births they wish to have, assuming all women are reproductive and sexually active at the same time.

With the population well sensitized to trigger conscious decision making with regards to contraceptive use, the service providers and continuous awareness creation will subsequently influence the couples to work towards the achievement of specific number of births within their means as opposed to mere natural child bearing with no control. It is therefore plausible to conclude that the improvement of the service delivery points towards efficiency, availability and uptake of birth control technologies is one of the most feasible means through which countries can fast track their fertility transitions. The access should not only take into consideration the quantity but also the quality of service and products available.

Service delivery for unconstrained access to contraception is therefore an important marker which policy can tackle for further improvement, with the index level acting as a proxy measure. The association between fertility preference implementation index and the unmet need to contraception suggests that this index can be used as an indicator for program success efforts. Going by the countries’ performances over time also taking into consideration the constants (such as reproductive age and economic situation) and non-constants (such as health system endowment), one can conclude that the current fertility transition witnessed in Sub-Saharan Africa is only but modest and a work in progress at the same time. Further research is recommended on how best the fertility preference implementation index can be used as a measure of service delivery for family planning program efforts.

Data availability

The datasets analyzed during the current study are available in the MEASURE DHS repository, (http://www.measuredhs.com). Access to the dataset requires registration, and is granted to those that wish to use the data for legitimate research purposes. A guide for how to apply for dataset access is available at: https://dhsprogram.com/data/Access-Instructions.cfm. The DHS datasets used in this study are shown in Table 1.

Comments on this article Comments (0)

Version 2
VERSION 2 PUBLISHED 14 Oct 2019
Comment
Author details Author details
Competing interests
Grant information
Copyright
Download
 
Export To
metrics
Views Downloads
F1000Research - -
PubMed Central
Data from PMC are received and updated monthly.
- -
Citations
CITE
how to cite this article
Otieno V, Agwanda A and Khasakhala A. Fertility transition in selected sub-Saharan African countries: the role of family planning programs [version 2; peer review: 2 approved]. F1000Research 2020, 8:1748 (https://doi.org/10.12688/f1000research.20585.2)
NOTE: If applicable, it is important to ensure the information in square brackets after the title is included in all citations of this article.
track
receive updates on this article
Track an article to receive email alerts on any updates to this article.

Open Peer Review

Current Reviewer Status: ?
Key to Reviewer Statuses VIEW
ApprovedThe paper is scientifically sound in its current form and only minor, if any, improvements are suggested
Approved with reservations A number of small changes, sometimes more significant revisions are required to address specific details and improve the papers academic merit.
Not approvedFundamental flaws in the paper seriously undermine the findings and conclusions
Version 2
VERSION 2
PUBLISHED 29 May 2020
Revised
Views
8
Cite
Reviewer Report 16 Jun 2020
Julianne Weis, Office of Population and Reproductive Health, USAID (United States Agency for International Development), Arlington, VA, USA 
Approved
VIEWS 8
I confirm that I have read this submission and believe that I have an ... Continue reading
CITE
CITE
HOW TO CITE THIS REPORT
Weis J. Reviewer Report For: Fertility transition in selected sub-Saharan African countries: the role of family planning programs [version 2; peer review: 2 approved]. F1000Research 2020, 8:1748 (https://doi.org/10.5256/f1000research.26795.r64108)
NOTE: it is important to ensure the information in square brackets after the title is included in all citations of this article.
Version 1
VERSION 1
PUBLISHED 14 Oct 2019
Views
16
Cite
Reviewer Report 24 Jan 2020
James Kiarie, Department of Reproductive Health and Research, World Health Organization (WHO), Geneva, Switzerland 
Approved
VIEWS 16
Abstract Background: “disparities amid almost similarities in policies is a cause of concern to demographers" – not sure what this is in reference to
 
Abstract Methods:
  • 'Using Bongaarts reformulation of Easterlin and Crimmins
... Continue reading
CITE
CITE
HOW TO CITE THIS REPORT
Kiarie J. Reviewer Report For: Fertility transition in selected sub-Saharan African countries: the role of family planning programs [version 2; peer review: 2 approved]. F1000Research 2020, 8:1748 (https://doi.org/10.5256/f1000research.22630.r57588)
NOTE: it is important to ensure the information in square brackets after the title is included in all citations of this article.
Views
27
Cite
Reviewer Report 15 Jan 2020
Julianne Weis, Office of Population and Reproductive Health, USAID (United States Agency for International Development), Arlington, VA, USA 
Approved with Reservations
VIEWS 27
This is a welcome exploration of a key source of debate in the FP/RH world: what is the more important source of fertility transition: population fertility preferences or contraception service delivery? The analysis was sound, but a qualified statistician needs ... Continue reading
CITE
CITE
HOW TO CITE THIS REPORT
Weis J. Reviewer Report For: Fertility transition in selected sub-Saharan African countries: the role of family planning programs [version 2; peer review: 2 approved]. F1000Research 2020, 8:1748 (https://doi.org/10.5256/f1000research.22630.r58569)
NOTE: it is important to ensure the information in square brackets after the title is included in all citations of this article.
  • Author Response 29 May 2020
    Vincent Otieno, Population Studies and Research Institute (PSRI), University of Nairobi, Nairobi, 00100, Kenya
    29 May 2020
    Author Response
    This is a welcome exploration of a key source of debate in the FP/RH world: what is the more important source of fertility transition: population fertility preferences or contraception service ... Continue reading
  • Author Response 29 May 2020
    Vincent Otieno, Population Studies and Research Institute (PSRI), University of Nairobi, Nairobi, 00100, Kenya
    29 May 2020
    Author Response
    All reviewer coments rectified
    Competing Interests: No competing interests were disclosed.
COMMENTS ON THIS REPORT
  • Author Response 29 May 2020
    Vincent Otieno, Population Studies and Research Institute (PSRI), University of Nairobi, Nairobi, 00100, Kenya
    29 May 2020
    Author Response
    This is a welcome exploration of a key source of debate in the FP/RH world: what is the more important source of fertility transition: population fertility preferences or contraception service ... Continue reading
  • Author Response 29 May 2020
    Vincent Otieno, Population Studies and Research Institute (PSRI), University of Nairobi, Nairobi, 00100, Kenya
    29 May 2020
    Author Response
    All reviewer coments rectified
    Competing Interests: No competing interests were disclosed.

Comments on this article Comments (0)

Version 2
VERSION 2 PUBLISHED 14 Oct 2019
Comment
Alongside their report, reviewers assign a status to the article:
Approved - the paper is scientifically sound in its current form and only minor, if any, improvements are suggested
Approved with reservations - A number of small changes, sometimes more significant revisions are required to address specific details and improve the papers academic merit.
Not approved - fundamental flaws in the paper seriously undermine the findings and conclusions
Sign In
If you've forgotten your password, please enter your email address below and we'll send you instructions on how to reset your password.

The email address should be the one you originally registered with F1000.

Email address not valid, please try again

You registered with F1000 via Google, so we cannot reset your password.

To sign in, please click here.

If you still need help with your Google account password, please click here.

You registered with F1000 via Facebook, so we cannot reset your password.

To sign in, please click here.

If you still need help with your Facebook account password, please click here.

Code not correct, please try again
Email us for further assistance.
Server error, please try again.